Introduction to Risk-Neutral Pricing Theory

I recently came across this QuantSE post where the author of the post tries to compute an expectation under the risk-neutral measure \(\mathbb{Q}\).

Risk-neutral pricing is a technique widely use in quantitative finance to compute  the values of derivatives product and I thought I could write a post  explaining what the theory is and how it can be used to compute a simple option’s price.

What is the Risk-Neutral Probability Measure?

Usually, probabilities on events are expressed in terms of the so-called “real world” probability measure \(\mathbb{P}\), i.e, if a stock can either move up or down, and that you think that there is an equal chance for it to go either way, you would say that it will go up with probability $p=\frac{1}{2}$.

However, when you want to compute the price of a financial asset \(X\) at time \(t=0\), you would do it through the computation of its expected value of its discounted future cash flows. The problem is that investors discount risk with different rates depending on their risk aversion (they require a risk-premium), and you would need to perform an adjustment which is very difficult to estimate.

Therefore we would like to be able to use a probability measure \(\mathbb{Q}\), equivalent to \(\mathbb{P}\) (i.e that agrees on events that cannot happen) under which the investor is insensitive to risk. This means that when computing expectations using \(\mathbb{Q}\),  we can discount cash flows using the risk-free rate \(r\).

Mathematically, this is described by saying that under the risk-neutral probability measure \(\mathbb{Q}\), discounted prices are martingales:

$$P(0,t) X_t = E_\mathbb{Q}[ P(0,T) X_T | \mathcal{F}_t]$$

Rearranging a bit and using \(P(0,t)=\frac{1}{(1+r)^t}\), you get:

$$(1+r)^{T-t}= E_\mathbb{Q}[ \frac{ X_T}{X_t}| \mathcal{F}_t]$$

That is, under \(\mathbb{Q}\), the expected value of the return on a asset \(X\) from \(t\) to \(T\) is the risk-free rate $r$ (compounded from \(t\) to \(T\)).

The risk-neutral probability measure is the probability measure that makes return on an investment the risk-free rate. It is “built” for that purpose.

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing (referred as FTAP thereafter) states that if markets are arbitrage-free and complete, then there exists a risk-neutral measure and it is unique  “A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing” (Freddy Delbaen and Walter Schachermayer, 1994).

How do we characterize the risk-neutral measure?

Let’s take a simple example. Assume a stock \(S\) in a single step framework, where the initial price is \(S_0\) . We define that after the single step, the price of the stock is either going up (in state \(u\)) \(S_1=S_0 \cdot u\) with probability \(p\) or going down  (in state \(d\)) \(S_1=S_0 \cdot d\) with probability \(1-p\) . Such a framework needs that \(d < 1+r < u \).

Let’s find the probability \(q\) such that discounted prices are martingales:

$$ \frac{1}{(1+r)^0} S_0 = E_\mathbb{Q}\left(\frac{S_1}{(1+r)^1} | \mathcal{F}_0 \right) = \frac{1}{1+r} \left( S_0 u q + S_0 d (1-q) \right) $$

Dividing by \(S_0\) and multiplying by $1+r$ on both sides , we get

$$ 1+r=  uq + d(1-q) = uq+ d -qd = d+q(u-d)$$

And we can find easily that:

$$ q = \frac{1+r-d}{u-d} $$

Ok, so we found the risk-neutral measure \(\mathbb{Q}\) for \(S\) by finding that \(\mathbb{Q}(S_1 = S_0 u) = q\) and hence \(\mathbb{Q}(S_1 = S_0 d) = 1-q\) .

How do we use the risk-neutral measure?

Now, assume we want to price a derivative product \(X\) which pays 1 if $S$ goes in state \(u\) and 0 otherwise.

Using the FTAP, we can write

$$X_0  = E_\mathbb{Q} \left(\frac{X_1}{(1+r)^1} | \mathcal{F}_0 \right) = \frac{1}{1+r} E_\mathbb{Q} \left(1_{\{S_1 = S_0 u\}} \right)
=\frac{1}{1+r} \mathbb{Q} \left( S_1 = S_0 u \right)$$

Note that by developing the possible outcomes of \(X_1\), we did not have to characterize the risk-neutral measure for \(X\).

Indeed, as we characterized \(\mathbb{Q}\) for \(S\), we can write:

$$X_0=\frac{1}{1+r} \mathbb{Q}
\left( S_1 = S_0 u \right)=\frac{1}{1+r} \frac{1+r-d}{u-d}$$

This way, we easily managed to find the value of the derivative product \(X_0\) without having to worry about risk-aversion and without having to even know the real-world probability measure \(\mathbb{P}\).

I hope you enjoyed this, I’ll be back with more CFA footage another time.

References

  1. Freddy Delbaen and Walter Schachermayer (1994), A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, (MATHEMATISCHE ANNALEN), , 463-520.

Comments

One response to “Introduction to Risk-Neutral Pricing Theory”

  1. Fabricio Avatar

    Dear Jérémie,

    I would like to thank you for this post. It was the best explanation about risk-neutral probability that I ever found in internet.

    Thanks,
    Fabricio

Leave a Reply

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.